Online annexe to:

“Multi-layered Perspective on the Barriers to Learning Participation of Disadvantaged Adults”

 


 

Sofie Cabus

KU LEUVEN HIVA,

Parkstraat 47, Leuven, Belgium,

sofie.cabus@kuleuven.be  

 

Petya Ilieva- Trichkova

Institute for the Study of Societies and Knowledge, Bulgarian Academy of Sciences,

Moskovska 13, 1000 Sofia, Bulgaria,

petya.ilievat@gmail.com  

 

Miroslav Štefánik

Centre of Social and Psychological Sciences, Slovak Academy of Sciences,

Sancova 56, 811 05 Bratislava, Slovakia,

miroslav.stefanik@savba.sk

 


This online annexe first provides descriptions and explanations to particular variables used in the explanatory model. In the appendix, additional evidence is provided on the data used (A) complete estimation results (B) and results from the sensitivity analysis (C). References to the tables in the appendix are made in the main text of the paper.

Structure of the annexe

1.        Explanatory model 2

1.1           Dependent variable. 2

1.2           Explanatory variables observed at the individual level 3

1.3           System characteristics observed at the regional or country level 6

2.        Appendix. 10

Table A1: Identified groups of interest among the employed population. 10

Table A2: Number of unweighted observations in the (EU-LFS 2016 dataset), by the type of AL activity. 10

Table A3: Descriptive statistics of the EU LFS sample, employed 25-64 years old, by country. 10

Table A4: Estimation results for individual characteristics (b/se/p) 12

Table A5: Estimation results for the household characteristics (b/se/p) 13

Table A6: Estimation results for the job characteristics (b/se/p) 14

Table A7: Estimation results for the employer´s characteristics (b/se/p) 15

Table A8: Estimation results for the role of system characteristics in AL participation (b/se/p) 16

Table B1: Descriptive statistics of the explanatory variables used in the models. 17

Table B2: Weighting of household member in computation of the Care index. 19

Table B3: Correlation coefficients among selected system determinants. 19

Table B4: Values of the Interclass correlation coefficient after a random intercept model of participation in AL. 19

Table B5: Estimates of the sub-equations of the model 20

Table B6: Models diagnostics. 21

Table C: Robustness of the estimates to changes in the construction of the main explanatory variables (Formal AL) 22

 

1.    Explanatory model

Our theoretical model assumed a regression type of model with one (main) dependent variable and a wide list of explanatory variables. For the sake of better orientation, we organize the explanatory variables in blocks. Namely referring to: characteristics of individuals, their household, job as well as employer observable at the level of individuals; and finally system-level characteristics - referring to policies or their outcomes observable at the national/regional level. Where feasible, explanatory variables are stylised to indicate potential barriers to AL.

 

1.1       Dependent variable

The dependent variable for further analysis is the AL participation rate. The definition of AL participation differs between available data sources surveying European households (EU-LFS and AES) (CEDEFOP 2015, p. 31). While the AES inquires about AL participation during the period of 12 months prior to the collection of the survey, EU-LFS asks about AL participation within the last four weeks prior to the surveying period. The surveying period of EU-LFS observations shifts randomly during the whole calendar year (to avoid biases caused by seasonality), with a quarterly data collection and sample components remaining in the sample for up to 4 quarters.

EU-LFS further allows a more precise distinction between learning activities by distinguishing between (i) formal and non-formal learning; and (ii) work-related and not work-related learning. Nevertheless, the information necessary to identify work-related AL was not collected in all 31 European countries. Therefore, we only distinguish between formal learning and non-formal learning activities.

Our dependent variable is collected at the level of individuals and have the form of a dummy variable which indicates whether the surveyed individuals did participate in the particular type of AL activity, during the 4 weeks reference period (1) or not (0).

 

In reality, some adults participate in both identified types of AL, formal as well as non-formal, during the 4 weeks reference period. Such cases present only 0.62% of the whole sample[1]. The construction of our dependent variables assesses adults separately for formal and non-formal AL.

 

Table 1: Proportions (in %) of employed adults (25-64 years) in the sample by AL participation status

 

Non-formal AL

Total

Not participated

Participated

 

Formal AL

Not participated

88.38

(1 421 300)

9.41

(151 300)

97.79

(1 572 600)

Participated

1.78

(28 600)

0.43

(6 900)

2.21

(35 500)

Total

90.16

(1 449 900)

9.84

(158 200)

100.00

(1 608 100)

Note: Shares in %, number of unweighted observations in the parenthesis (rounded to hundreds)

Source: EU-LFS 2016

 

In absolute terms, the dataset includes over 1.6 million observations of employed adults aged 25-64. Approximately 28.6 thousand adults participated in formal education and more than 151 thousand adults in non-formal learning activities. Approximately, 6,900 individuals combine formal education with non-formal learning activities.

 

1.2       Explanatory variables observed at the individual level

Although the existing literature on AL participation often considers barriers to AL participation (Section 2), our data limit us to construct variables purely based on available characteristics. However, based on the previous literature, we are able to construct proxies for barriers to AL participation, for example, situational barriers can be captured by the characteristics of the household, like having small children. We also consider individual characteristics (e.g. migrant status, female vs male) and characteristics of the job. Institutional barriers are easily collected from the official statistics such as Eurostat or the World Bank; some institutional barriers were constructed by using EU LFS. Dispositional barriers cannot be identified directly in the EU-LFS data and had to be approximated. For example, the flexibility of the labour market can be captured by considering the share of persons in temporary contracts at the regional level and the dismissal rate at the regional level is a good proxy of the level of employment protection. We believe to provide some information on the dispositional barriers by looking specifically at the disadvantaged groups. A basic overview of the model is displayed in Scheme A (appendix). As follows, we first focus on the construction of individual-level characteristics of households, individuals and their jobs.

a. Household characteristics

For the household related barriers, we construct two indexes grasping the mechanisms behind deciding on the final number of working hours: (1) the Care index; and (2) the Share of non-earners in the household.

 

Care index  - The Care index quantifies the need for allocating time to carrying activities within the household. In computing this index we take into account the number of children and elderly in the household of the responding (employed) person (See Table 2). When summing the number of household members in the index, individuals are ascribed a different weight based on their age.

 

Table 2: Weighting of a household member in the computation of the Care index 

Age of the household member

Weight of the household member

0-4

4

5-9

3

10-14

2

15-19

1

20-59

0

60-74

1

75-84

2

85+

3

 

 

Weights of household members are ascribed arbitrary, assuming a different intensity of carrying activities based on the age of the household member. The Care index enters the model separately for males and females. First, we explore its association with the number of actual working hours during the reference period. Here we expect, a negative association between the Care index and AL participation, more pronounced in the case of females.

 

Share of non-earners in the household -The second index constructed out of the information observable for the household is the proportion of non-earners among the household members. The values of the index also enter in the model separately for males and females. Similarly, we first explore its association with the working hours and in the second step with the AL participation. We assume that especially for males, the association with working hours is going to be positive, as more non-earners in the household should press on male members of the household to work more working hours.

 

Working hours - Here, the sum of actual working hours from all declared jobs is used. The time period for which the actual working hours are inquired is the same as the reference period for which AL participation is indicated.

We assume a negative trade-off between work and formal AL because time is a limited resource and in the case of formal learning, it is not allocable simultaneously to work and AL. This is different for the non-formal AL, while a dominant share of it is being delivered at the workplace. More working hours may, thus, lead to higher participation in non-formal AL.

 

b. Job characteristics

Out of the information on occupation in the current job, we construct four variables: (1) over-education index; (2) mean probability of computerization; (3) high-skill occupation (dummy); and (4) Supervision (dummy).

Over-education index - To construct the over-education index, we first create an individual specific variable for years of schooling. This is an estimate based on the year of graduation of individual  with regard to the highest level of education attained by this individual, and relative to his/her year of birth:

 

HATYEAR denotes the year when the highest level of education was successfully completed; YEAR the year of the data collection (in our case 2016); AGE the age of the individual respondent; and ENTRANCE_PRIMARY the official entrance age in compulsory education (country-specific). The subscript  denotes the individual.

In the next step, we construct the variable median years of schooling. This variable indicates how long it takes for an individual  living in country  and enrolled in a particular educational track  to graduate from that educational level. We express the duration in the median years of schooling as to account for extreme values.

 

Using a similar approach, we also construct the median years of schooling for an individual in occupation and accounting for differences across countries:

 

Subscript o denotes each code from the International Standard Classification of Occupations (ISCO). The EU LFS edition 2017 provides us with ISCO 3-digit.

Finally, the over-education index is the difference between individuals´ median years of schooling, which has been determined by the highest level of education attained, and the occupational median years of schooling observed for all individuals within the occupational group defined at the level of ISCO 3-digit. We then may write:

 

The over-education index is included in the model separately for individuals working in a low-skilled and high-skilled occupation. This should allow us to explore different dynamics in the association between over-education and AL participation conditional on the complexity of the current job.

Two possible directions of the association between over-education and AL participation can be assumed. Either those who are overeducated in their current job, are overeducated because they have a higher propensity (motivation) to acquire more education for which they are more likely to participate in AL; or in the contrary, underutilizing the already acquired education in the current job leads to a decline in the propensity (motivation) to seek further education and thus participating in AL.

 

Mean risk of computerization - The variable of the mean probability of computerization is created using the probabilities of computerization estimated in Frey and Osborne (2016). They use the US occupational database of job descriptions - O*NET. Occupation specific probability of computerization is quantified based on an assessment of the tasks and job descriptions from O*NET in the context of the expected advances in machine learning and robotics. Authors report the probability of computerization for the occupations coded in the Standard Occupational Classification (SOC). The SOC classification can be translated into the International Standard Classification of Occupations (ISCO) used in the EU-LFS. When shifting to a different level of detail we use the mean probability of computerization estimated for all the occupations within the concerned occupational group assuming equal weight for each of the sub-occupations.

 

High-skilled occupation - The high skilled occupation is defined by the occupational group of ISCO 1 to ISCO4. The occupational classification ISCO is coded hierarchically in terms of the complexity of the tasks performed in the occupation. Occupations coded in the group ISCO 1 are the most complex, require the highest level of skills and education; an occupational group of ISCO 9 shelters the least complex occupations. Although the risk of computerization shows a small negative correlation with the occupational complexity, risk of computerization also appears in the most complex occupations.

We assume that for individuals in occupations with higher complexity of tasks, the need for further learning is higher.

 

Supervision - Finally, we use a dummy for whether the job of the responding person involves supervising duties. Here we assume, that supervising duties are linked with more responsibility, but also a need for additional job-related training. On the other hand, supervising is connected with a more demanding job and, therefore, leaves less time to work-unrelated AL activities.

 

c. Individual characteristics

In addition to the barriers to AL identified at the individual level and the system determinants identified at the regional or country level, we construct variables measuring the characteristics of individuals. These characteristics are considered important control variables for inclusion in the multi-layered empirical framework. Here we include the “usual suspects” available in the EU-LFS questionnaire, namely: Gender (dummy); Age (continuous); Level of education; Level of urbanization.

Occupation related information is explored in the case of the job-related barriers and was therefore not included in the list of control variables.

d. Employer’s characteristics

Job-related AL significantly differs based on the characteristics of the employer. The EU-LFS data allow us to identify the sector of economic activity as well as constructing a proxy for an employer’s size[2]. Those two variables appear to be the strongest factors explaining the provision of job-related AL by employers (CEDEFOP 2015). Additionally, we have complemented the set of employer’s characteristics by the variable indicating whether the employed person is looking for another job. Since we do control for a relatively rich list of job-related characteristics, we consider “looking for a job” to be an overall assessment of actual working conditions.

1.3       System characteristics observed at the regional or country level

In selecting the relevant system-level determinants of AL participation, we depart from the model outlined in Groenez et al. (2007). Because of the high collinearity between some of the system level determinants, we are first accounting for associations between them in order to obtain unbiased coefficients for each of their direct associations with the dependent variable.

a. Subjective assessment of costs being the main obstacle in AL participation

In between the individual and system level of variables lies the assessment of costs being the main obstacle in AL participation. This variable is constructed based on the data from the AES, collected for 2016 [Data code: trng_aes_179]. Its values present the share of the interviewed persons identifying costs to be the main obstacle in AL participation. [Data code: trng_aes_179] 

b. Demography

Here we decided to use only one variable, the regional mean age of the population computed by using the EU-LFS microdata for 2016. It reflects the extent to which society suffers from ageing. As the returns AL decreases with higher age, older societies may invest less in AL than the younger ones (Groenez et al., 2007). This may be especially true for formal AL as this is more often accredited and thus to a higher extent recognized at the labour market.

The originally included variable of the mean number of household members under 25 was later excluded from the model because it was not showing any significant association.

c. Initial education

The shape of the system of initial education to a substantial extent determines AL participation. We grasp the main shape of the system by four variables: a) the years of compulsory schooling; b) age of entrance into lower secondary education; c) the share of students at the upper secondary level in vocational programmes; d) public expenditures on education as a per cent share on GDP.

The years of compulsory schooling are based on the UNESCO UIS.Stat database. It varies at the country level and grasps the international differences in the amount of initial schooling provided by the state. We have considered to include also the average years of schooling averaged at the regional level, but the years of compulsory schooling showed to be explanatory stronger. All the system level variables in the area of initial education are, thus, collected at the level of countries; and refer rather to the design of the educational policies, than to the outcomes of these policies.

A wide list of studies documents a positive association between initial schooling and AL participation at the country level (OECD 2003; Brunello, 2001; Jung & Cervero, 2002; Bassanini et al. 2005; Wöβmann & Schütz, 2006). Given this, we expect to observe a positive association also at the individual level.

The age of entrance into lower secondary education determines the age at which pupils are being selected into specialised educational programmes – educational tracks. When this age is higher, the ratio of skills received by pupils within initial schooling is more in favour of general than specialized skills. When exploring available literature, Groenez et al. (2007) find support for both of the directions of the association between the level of specialization in initial schooling and AL participation, namely: less specialized and more general systems of initial education precondition higher AL participation because of the lack of specialized skills received during initial education (Antikainen, 2006; Brunello, 2006); and more specialised and less general systems of initial education precondition higher AL participation because of specialised skills getting obsolete faster than general skills (Bassanini et al., 2005).

d. Labour market

Among the system determinants in the area of labour market, we use the regional employment rate of the main age group (25-64), based on the EU-LFS; regional share of employed persons aged 25-64 who have a temporary contract type, based on the EU-LFS; regional share of persons who were dismissed or were made redundant in their last job or business, based on the EU-LFS; country-level active labour market policy expenditures on training (LMP type 2) as a share of GDP, based on the Labour Market Policy Database administrated by Eurostat.

The employment rate is strongly positively correlated with regional GDP, for what we have accounted in the model by implementing an association path between the employment rate and regional GDP. The regional employment rate is also endogenous in the model, allowing its association with other labour market system determinants (share of dismissals, the share of temporary contracts, ALMP expenditures on training), public expenditures on education and the number of years in compulsory education.

Based on Groenez and co-authors (2007) we assume that AL participation might be higher in regions with higher employment rate mainly because the workplace generates an additional supply of training (which is true mostly for what we consider here as the non-formal training) (McGivney, 2001); adults are more confident that learning will be utilised in a better job (McGivney, 2001); companies invest more in human capital when confronted with shortages of skilled labour (Gorard & Rees, 2002).

Although we control for individual-level working hours, the regional share of temporary contracts is included to proxy for the employment legislation. Lassnigg (2005) and McGivney (2001) hint that employers are less willing to invest in AL of employees working under part-time or temporary contracts, which might imply a lower regional supply of AL.    

The share of dismissals is used as a proxy for employment protection (flexibility). We assume that both sides - employers and employees - are more willing to invest in AL if employment protection is higher. More flexible labour markets allow flexible hiring and dismissal to compensate for potential skills shortages or obsolescence.

Active labour market policy expenditures on training present alternative support to the supply of AL as the programmes financed from these resources might target unemployed as well as employed. 

e. Economy

Exploring their empirical associations, we have limited the number of economy-related system determinants of AL to only two, namely: the Gross domestic product (GDP) at current market prices by NUTS 2 regions in euro per inhabitant, based on the Statistics of National Accounts published by Eurostat; and patent applications to the European patent office (EPO), published by Eurostat.

The GDP indicator is always a “central” indicator when considering various aspects of the economy, such as the openness, labour productivity etc. An aspect of special importance, in the context of AL participation, is the innovation intensity of the production. Here we capture this aspect using the indicator of the number of patent applications to the European patent office.

Groenez and co-authors (2007) estimate multiple specifications of explanatory models on AL participation and inequality in AL participation. They identify the level of innovation as one of the key system determinants appearing as significant in all of their model specifications. Its possible association with AL participation is assumed. An overview of the descriptive statistics of the explanatory variables is provided in Table B1 of the Appendix.

 

 

 


 

2.    Appendix

Table A1: Identified groups of interest among the employed population

Group of interest

Age of participants

Highest education attained

All

25-64

All

Low-educated adults

25-64

≤ ISCED 2

Low-educated young adults

20-29

≤ ISCED 2

Migrants

25-64

All

Source: From the authors.

 

Table A2: Number of unweighted observations in the (EU-LFS 2016 dataset), by the type of AL activity

Groups of interest

Observations in the sample (Unweighted)

Population (Weighted)

Participation rate - Formal AL (%)

Participation rate - Non-formal AL (%)

Population 25-64

2 247 000

274 220 800

3.16

8.43

Employed adults 25-64

1 608 100

200 844 000

2.58

9.91

Low-educated adults 25-64

276 400

34 859 600

0.89

4.23

Low-educated young adults 20-29

31 600

4 958 200

13.37

5.77

Employed migrants 25-64

171 600

25 879 800

3.35

8.20

Note: Groups are identified based on the definitions in Table A1

Source: EU-LFS 2016

 

Table A3: Descriptive statistics of the EU LFS sample, employed 25-64 years old, by country

Observations in the sample (Unweighted)

Population (Weighted)

Participation rate - Formal AL (%)

Participation rate - Non-formal AL (%)

Austria

76 394

3 641 500

3.3

12.2

Belgium

37 774

4 243 400

1.5

5.6

Bulgaria

13 000

2 822 200

0.9

0.4

Croatia

10 425

1 445 300

1.3

1.0

Cyprus

15 829

328 800

1.9

4.7

Czech Republic

16 986

4 730 100

1.5

10.2

Denmark

39 348

2 323 900

5.9

24.1

Estonia

10 370

563 000

3.9

12.1

Finland

10 410

2 119 900

7.9

22.4

France

168 895

23 599 300

1.2

20.0

Germany

228 657

36 815 300

2.6

5.9

Greece

75 192

3 472 500

1.2

2.1

Hungary

87 138

4 008 300

0.7

6.1

Italy

186 196

21 263 700

1.1

7.8

Latvia

15 814

800 200

1.9

5.1

Lithuania

25 384

1 212 500

1.2

5.3

Luxembourg

13 471

245 400

1.8

16.0

Malta

9 171

164 800

4.2

5.2

Netherlands

34 920

6 970 800

6.1

14.9

Norway

11 478

2 221 700

4.5

16.2

Poland

114 362

14 764 900

1.4

2.6

Portugal

61 256

4 108 800

1.8

7.4

Romania

89 006

7 684 100

0.1

0.9

Slovak Republic

35 722

2 311 400

0.7

2.1

Slovenia

24 897

844 900

4.1

9.0

Spain

34 868

17 378 900

3.2

7.4

Sweden

129 942

4 214 900

5.0

25.1

United Kingdom

31 190

26 543 700

3.4

13.1

Total

1 608 095

200 843 900

2.6

9.9

Note: Population of employed, 25-64 years old in the sample, using sampling weights, individuals may combine participation in formal and non-formal AL. Rates in %, numbers rounded to hundreds.

Source: EU-LFS 2016

 

 

 


 

 

Table A4: Estimation results for individual characteristics (b/se/p)

Target group

Employed

All

Low-educated

Young and

low-educated

Migrants

Type of AL

Formal

Non-formal

Formal

Non-formal

Formal

Non-formal

Formal

Non-formal

Female

-0.033

0.241

0.069

0.140

-0.109

-0.175

-0.027

0.194

0.045

0.029

0.121

0.075

0.194

0.192

0.093

0.071

0.457

0.000

0.570

0.061

0.575

0.362

0.773

0.006

Age

-0.099

-0.008

-0.103

-0.016

(omitted)

(omitted)

-0.095

-0.014

0.007

0.001

0.010

0.002

 

0.009

0.003

0.000

0.000

0.000

0.000

 

 

0.000

0.000

Level of education

(primary omitted)

Lower secondary

-0.029

0.276

(omitted)

(omitted)

(omitted)

(omitted)

0.010

0.396

0.105

0.039

 

 

0.130

0.106

0.785

0.000

 

 

 

 

0.938

0.000

Upper secondary

0.496

0.376

(omitted)

(omitted)

(omitted)

(omitted)

0.488

0.411

0.075

0.045

 

 

0.137

0.076

0.000

0.000

 

 

0.000

0.000

Tertiary

0.446

0.504

(omitted)

(omitted)

(omitted)

(omitted)

0.343

0.561

0.105

0.075

 

 

0.164

0.111

0.000

0.000

 

 

0.037

0.000

Degree of urbanization

(City omitted)

Town

-0.295

-0.055

-0.019

0.029

0.113

0.135

-0.263

-0.009

0.045

0.025

0.095

0.067

0.154

0.171

0.074

0.068

0.000

0.025

0.845

0.663

0.461

0.429

0.000

0.898

Rural

-0.428

-0.057

0.071

0.168

0.255

0.172

-0.308

0.041

0.051

0.026

0.121

0.063

0.207

0.205

0.099

0.067

0.000

0.026

0.556

0.008

0.219

0.400

0.002

0.539

Legend: b/se/p

Source: EU-LFS 2016

 

 


 

Table A5: Estimation results for the household characteristics (b/se/p)

Target group

Employed

All

Low-educated

Young and

Migrants

low-educated

Type of AL

Formal

Non-formal

Formal

Non-formal

Formal

Non-formal

Formal

Non-formal

Household related barriers

Female*care index

-0.092

-0.023

-0.044

-0.026

-0.072

0.015

-0.074

-0.028

0.011

0.003

0.020

0.012

0.027

0.033

0.026

0.007

0.000

0.000

0.027

0.032

0.009

0.647

0.005

0.000

Male*care index

-0.071

-0.004

-0.075

-0.014

-0.083

-0.013

-0.066

-0.004

0.008

0.004

0.022

0.009

0.039

0.034

0.021

0.010

0.000

0.292

0.001

0.115

0.034

0.706

0.001

0.694

Male*non earners in the HH

0.163

-0.305

-0.294

-0.277

-0.651

-0.457

0.183

-0.327

0.082

0.050

0.238

0.116

0.406

0.446

0.229

0.135

0.047

0.000

0.217

0.017

0.108

0.306

0.425

0.015

Female*non earners in the HH

0.377

-0.167

-0.053

-0.458

0.204

-0.269

0.660

-0.083

0.077

0.046

0.263

0.143

0.543

0.607

0.235

0.112

0.000

0.000

0.840

0.001

0.707

0.657

0.005

0.461

Working hours

-0.014

0.010

-0.008

0.009

-0.008

0.005

-0.018

0.007

0.002

0.001

0.003

0.001

0.003

0.006

0.002

0.001

0.000

0.000

0.001

0.000

0.019

0.432

0.000

0.000

Legend: b/se/p

Source: EU-LFS 2016


 

Table A6: Estimation results for the job characteristics (b/se/p)

Target group

Employed

All

Low-educated

Young and

Migrants

low-educated

Type of AL

Formal

Non-formal

Formal

Non-formal

Formal

Non-formal

Formal

Non-formal

Job related barriers

Low-skilled*Over-education

0.088

0.051

0.059

0.008

0.093

0.037

0.085

0.060

0.012

0.009

0.019

0.016

0.031

0.023

0.015

0.013

0.000

0.000

0.001

0.610

0.003

0.116

0.000

0.000

High-skilled*Over-education

0.001

0.039

0.077

0.020

0.030

-0.005

0.014

0.031

0.010

0.006

0.033

0.019

0.042

0.044

0.016

0.010

0.880

0.000

0.018

0.294

0.473

0.907

0.377

0.002

Risk of computerisation

-0.268

-0.283

-0.550

-0.087

0.056

0.355

-0.011

-0.373

0.055

0.024

0.179

0.095

0.265

0.300

0.117

0.072

0.000

0.000

0.002

0.359

0.832

0.237

0.926

0.000

High skilled occupation (dummy)

0.314

0.446

0.519

0.568

0.531

0.352

0.421

0.520

0.053

0.026

0.152

0.084

0.203

0.258

0.102

0.057

0.000

0.000

0.001

0.000

0.009

0.173

0.000

0.000

Supervision (dummy)

-0.077

0.264

-0.103

0.406

-0.510

0.230

-0.088

0.316

0.034

0.017

0.173

0.060

0.279

0.264

0.094

0.060

0.022

0.000

0.553

0.000

0.067

0.385

0.348

0.000

Legend: b/se/p

Source: EU-LFS 2016


 

Table A7: Estimation results for the employer´s characteristics (b/se/p)

Target group

Employed

All

Low-educated

Young and low-educated

Migrants

Type of AL

Formal

Non-formal

Formal

Non-formal

Formal

Non-formal

Formal

Non-formal

Looking for a job

0.304

0.257

0.503

0.466

-0.598

0.390

0.171

0.266

0.053

0.030

0.200

0.098

0.218

0.264

0.095

0.080

0.000

0.000

0.012

0.000

0.006

0.140

0.070

0.001

Economic sector (Public services omitted)

Agriculture

-0.765

-0.624

-1.183

-0.880

-0.526

-0.770

-0.973

-0.849

0.122

0.063

0.243

0.136

0.387

0.468

0.310

0.308

0.000

0.000

0.000

0.000

0.174

0.100

0.002

0.006

Industry

-0.820

-0.357

-0.731

-0.426

-0.381

-0.445

-1.002

-0.436

0.042

0.044

0.147

0.075

0.171

0.188

0.102

0.072

0.000

0.000

0.000

0.000

0.026

0.018

0.000

0.000

Construction

-0.974

-0.585

-1.071

-0.641

-0.755

-0.463

-1.552

-0.742

0.067

0.047

0.209

0.090

0.239

0.327

0.234

0.145

0.000

0.000

0.000

0.000

0.002

0.157

0.000

0.000

Private services

-0.543

-0.338

-0.792

-0.480

-0.347

-0.561

-0.636

-0.402

0.034

0.033

0.108

0.058

0.149

0.178

0.094

0.067

0.000

0.000

0.000

0.000

0.019

0.002

0.000

0.000

Number of employees in the local unit (over 50 omitted)

Less than 10

-0.115

-0.147

-0.139

-0.337

0.147

0.097

-0.163

-0.218

0.025

0.016

0.141

0.047

0.194

0.170

0.097

0.044

0.000

0.000

0.323

0.000

0.451

0.567

0.091

0.000

11 to 20

-0.045

-0.075

0.219

-0.015

0.464

0.093

0.026

-0.080

0.029

0.023

0.141

0.070

0.250

0.231

0.092

0.070

0.125

0.001

0.121

0.834

0.063

0.687

0.778

0.252

21 to 50

-0.118

-0.009

0.028

-0.005

0.250

0.216

-0.185

-0.126

0.040

0.018

0.133

0.054

0.167

0.188

0.131

0.072

0.003

0.607

0.832

0.930

0.133

0.251

0.157

0.080

Legend: b/se/p

Source: EU-LFS 2016


 

Table A8: Estimation results for the role of system characteristics in AL participation (b/se/p)

Target group

Employed

All

Low educated

Young and low-educated

Migrants

Type of AL

Formal

Non-formal

Formal

Non-formal

Formal

Non-formal

Formal

Non-formal

Costs of AL

0.017

0.047

-0.084

0.102

-0.148

0.132

-0.006

0.062

0.013

0.016

0.023

0.022

0.040

0.031

0.016

0.021

0.172

0.003

0.000

0.000

0.000

0.000

0.725

0.003

Demography

Mean age of the

-0.033

0.031

-0.042

0.048

-0.019

0.112

-0.014

0.028

regional population

0.014

0.018

0.024

0.026

0.036

0.029

0.017

0.028

 

0.019

0.094

0.087

0.059

0.595

0.000

0.414

0.313

Initial education

Years of compulsory

-0.145

-0.350

-0.029

-0.326

0.064

-0.418

-0.254

-0.224

schooling

0.049

0.064

0.069

0.094

0.112

0.104

0.044

0.065

 

0.003

0.000

0.672

0.000

0.569

0.000

0.000

0.001

Entrance age into

0.249

0.009

0.397

0.107

0.302

0.043

0.185

0.067

lower secondary education

0.047

0.058

0.103

0.098

0.139

0.105

0.057

0.080

 

0.000

0.873

0.000

0.275

0.030

0.684

0.001

0.397

Share of students in

0.008

0.005

-0.004

0.003

-0.022

-0.008

0.013

0.000

vocational programmes

0.004

0.005

0.006

0.007

0.009

0.008

0.005

0.005

 

0.059

0.350

0.504

0.708

0.017

0.321

0.004

0.956

Government expenditure on

-0.002

0.655

0.452

0.919

0.617

0.514

0.572

0.719

education as a % of GDP

0.166

0.143

0.271

0.228

0.481

0.292

0.181

0.229

 

0.988

0.000

0.095

0.000

0.200

0.078

0.002

0.002

Labour market

Employment rate

0.004

0.006

0.005

0.011

-0.011

0.023

0.001

0.023

0.004

0.005

0.008

0.009

0.011

0.011

0.006

0.007

0.325

0.234

0.538

0.213

0.299

0.032

0.826

0.001

Share of dismissals

0.003

0.005

-0.023

0.003

-0.018

-0.017

-0.006

0.004

0.004

0.005

0.007

0.007

0.011

0.012

0.005

0.007

0.542

0.336

0.001

0.644

0.111

0.147

0.251

0.549

Share of temporary contracts

0.009

-0.024

0.044

-0.009

0.038

0.008

0.019

-0.022

0.010

0.009

0.018

0.012

0.029

0.027

0.014

0.013

0.368

0.009

0.013

0.469

0.179

0.766

0.172

0.088

Active Labour Market Policy expenditure on Training

0.050

0.101

-0.205

0.146

-0.046

0.076

-0.196

0.126

0.035

0.034

0.067

0.036

0.107

0.059

0.048

0.044

0.151

0.003

0.002

0.000

0.669

0.196

0.000

0.004

Economy

Regional GDP

0.417

-0.033

0.523

-0.346

0.150

0.311

-0.090

-0.262

0.163

0.143

0.259

0.188

0.431

0.306

0.154

0.198

0.010

0.816

0.043

0.065

0.728

0.310

0.556

0.186

Number of patent

0.079

0.287

0.081

0.313

0.125

0.307

0.176

0.210

applications

0.052

0.070

0.062

0.105

0.100

0.115

0.042

0.082

 

0.124

0.000

0.188

0.003

0.213

0.008

0.000

0.010

Legend: b/se/p

Source: EU-LFS 2016

 

 


 

Table B1: Descriptive statistics of the explanatory variables used in the models

Variable

Mean

Std. Dev.

Min

Max

Status

Individual characteristics

Female

0.47

0.50

0

1

Ex.

Age

44.54

10.40

27

62

Ex.

Level of education

Lower_secondary

0.14

0.34

0

1

Ex.

Upper_secondary

0.36

0.48

0

1

Ex.

Tertiary

0.33

0.47

0

1

Ex.

Degree of urbanization

Town

0.31

0.46

0

1

Ex.

Rural

0.35

0.48

0

1

Ex.

Household characteristics

Female*Care index

1.01

2.18

0

12

Ex.

Male*Care index

1.19

2.37

0

11

Ex.

Male*Non earners in the HH

0.11

0.19

0

0.95

Ex.

Female*Non earners in the HH

0.08

0.18

0

0.95

Ex.

Working hours

34.36

15.55

0

80

End.

Job characteristics

Low-skilled*Over-education

-0.97

3.02

-10

7

Ex.

High-skilled*Over-education

1.01

3.09

-10

7

Ex.

Risk of computerisation

0.55

0.30

0

0.97

Ex.

High skilled occupation (dummy)

0.51

0.50

0

1

Ex.

Supervision

0.17

0.38

0

1

Ex.

Employer´s characteristics

Looking for a job

0.03

0.18

0

1

Ex.

Economic sector

Agriculture

0.06

0.24

0

1

Ex.

Industry

0.18

0.38

0

1

Ex.

Construction

0.07

0.25

0

1

Ex.

Private services

0.37

0.48

0

1

Ex.

Public services

0.32

0.47

0

1

Ex.

Number of employees in the local unit

Less than 10

0.23

0.42

0

1

Ex.

11 to 20

0.10

0.30

0

1

Ex.

21 to 50

0.14

0.34

0

1

Ex.

Over 50

0.42

0.49

0

1

Ex.

System characteristic

Costs of AL

6.09

2.96

2.3

15

Ex.

Demography

Mean age of the regional population

42.36

2.26

34.06

49.84

Ex.

Initial education

Years of compulsory schooling

10.52

1.39

8

12

Ex.

Entrance age into lower secondary education

11.39

1.04

10

13

Ex.

Share of students in vocational programmes

47.37

12.79

12.72

73.21

Ex.

Government expenditure on education as a % of GDP

1.57

0.18

1.22

1.93

End.

Labour market

Employment rate

72.46

8.04

45.85

88.39

End.

Share of dismissals

19.74

6.68

4.00

46.44

Ex.

Share of temporary contracts

7.43

4.05

0.12

17.98

Ex.

Active Labour Market Policy expenditure on Training

2.08

1.60

-2.30

3.97

Ex.

Economy

Regional GDP

10.06

0.64

8.32

11.42

End.

Number of patent applications

7.26

1.97

1.52

9.89

End.

Note:

Ex. – variable is exogenous variable in the model (it is only associated with the dependent variable);

End. – variable is endogenous (it is associated with the dependent variable and also predicted by other variables  

Source: EU-LFS 2016


 

Table B2: Weighting of household member in computation of the Care index 

Age of the household member

Weight of the household member

0-4

4

5-9

3

10-14

2

15-19

1

20-59

0

60-74

1

75-84

2

85+

3

 

Table B3: Correlation coefficients among selected system determinants

Years of compulsory schooling

Share of students in vocational programmes

Government expenditure on education as a % of GDP

Employment rate

Active Labour Market Policy expenditure on Training

Regional GDP

Share of students in

vocational programmes

0.348

Government expenditure on

education as a % of GDP

-0.271

-0.226

Employment rate

-0.419

-0.056

0.345

Active Labour Market Policy

expenditure on Training

0.067

0.158

0.344

0.126

Regional GDP

0.275

0.156

0.333

-0.020

0.614

Number of patent applications

0.606

0.145

0.021

-0.198

0.500

0.640

Source: EU-LFS 2016

 

Table B4: Values of the Interclass correlation coefficient after a random intercept model of participation in AL

Level of random intercept

Employed

All

Low skilled

Young low -skilled

Migrant

Country

0.183

0.366

0.464

0.223

Region

0.185

0.399

0.515

0.222

Note: Retrieved from a 10% sample of the database

Source: EU-LFS 2016

 

 


 

Table B5: Estimates of the sub-equations of the model

Target group

Employed

All

Low skilled

Young and low-skilled

Migrants

Type of AL

Formal

Non-formal

Formal

Non-formal

Formal

Non-formal

Formal

Non-formal

Dependent: Working hours

Female*care index

-0.036

-0.036

-0.031

-0.031

-0.044

-0.044

-0.044

-0.044

0.003

0.003

0.003

0.003

0.007

0.007

0.005

0.005

0.000

0.000

0.000

0.000

0.000

0.000

0.000

0.000

Male*care index

0.012

0.012

0.010

0.010

0.008

0.008

0.007

0.007

0.001

0.001

0.001

0.001

0.002

0.002

0.001

0.001

0.000

0.000

0.000

0.000

0.000

0.000

0.000

0.000

Male*not earners

 in the HH

0.114

0.114

0.125

0.125

0.044

0.044

0.078

0.078

0.007

0.007

0.012

0.012

0.029

0.029

0.016

0.016

0.000

0.000

0.000

0.000

0.122

0.122

0.000

0.000

Female*not earners

 in the HH

-0.087

-0.087

-0.227

-0.227

-0.110

-0.110

-0.160

-0.160

0.015

0.015

0.017

0.017

0.057

0.057

0.021

0.021

0.000

0.000

0.000

0.000

0.055

0.055

0.000

0.000

Constatnt

3.542

3.542

3.517

3.517

3.544

3.544

3.529

3.529

0.006

0.006

0.009

0.009

0.011

0.011

0.012

0.012

0.000

0.000

0.000

0.000

0.000

0.000

0.000

0.000

Dependent: Employment rate

Public expenditures on

education

2.162

2.162

4.326

4.326

3.400

3.400

3.143

3.143

1.408

1.408

1.475

1.475

1.545

1.545

1.529

1.529

0.125

0.125

0.003

0.003

0.028

0.028

0.040

0.040

Years of compulsory

schooling

-2.036

-2.036

-2.009

-2.009

-1.703

-1.703

-1.049

-1.049

0.730

0.730

0.723

0.723

0.808

0.808

0.853

0.853

0.005

0.005

0.005

0.005

0.035

0.035

0.219

0.219

Active Labour Market

Policy expenditure

 on Training

-2.546

-2.546

-12.837

-12.837

-12.701

-12.701

-9.482

-9.482

6.826

6.826

7.318

7.318

7.292

7.292

7.076

7.076

0.709

0.709

0.079

0.079

0.082

0.082

0.180

0.180

Share of dismissals

-0.296

-0.296

-0.182

-0.182

-0.181

-0.181

-0.020

-0.020

0.130

0.130

0.100

0.100

0.120

0.120

0.124

0.124

0.023

0.023

0.070

0.070

0.130

0.130

0.874

0.874

Share of temporary

Contracts

-0.438

-0.438

-0.175

-0.175

-0.321

-0.321

-0.458

-0.458

0.170

0.170

0.167

0.167

0.171

0.171

0.203

0.203

0.010

0.010

0.295

0.295

0.060

0.060

0.024

0.024

Constatnt

94.284

94.284

81.404

81.404

83.502

83.502

75.195

75.195

11.482

11.482

11.204

11.204

12.898

12.898

13.173

13.173

0.000

0.000

0.000

0.000

0.000

0.000

0.000

0.000

Dependent: Public expenditures in education

Years of compulsory

 Schooling

-0.043

-0.043

-0.002

-0.002

0.040

0.040

-0.070

-0.070

0.039

0.039

0.055

0.055

0.053

0.053

0.067

0.067

0.262

0.262

0.978

0.978

0.453

0.453

0.300

0.300

Mean age of the

regional population

-0.003

-0.003

-0.010

-0.010

-0.015

-0.015

-0.010

-0.010

0.022

0.022

0.028

0.028

0.026

0.026

0.022

0.022

0.885

0.885

0.725

0.725

0.566

0.566

0.648

0.648

Entrance age into

lower secondary education

0.381

0.381

0.333

0.333

0.427

0.427

0.416

0.416

0.049

0.049

0.084

0.084

0.072

0.072

0.081

0.081

0.000

0.000

0.000

0.000

0.000

0.000

0.000

0.000

Constatnt

0.986

0.986

1.213

1.213

-0.002

-0.002

1.266

1.266

0.937

0.937

1.449

1.449

1.264

1.264

1.534

1.534

0.293

0.293

0.403

0.403

0.999

0.999

0.409

0.409

Dependent: Regional GDP

Employment rate

0.008

0.008

0.005

0.005

0.005

0.005

0.012

0.012

0.005

0.005

0.006

0.006

0.006

0.006

0.006

0.006

0.133

0.133

0.463

0.463

0.400

0.400

0.046

0.046

Number of patent applications

0.285

0.285

0.257

0.257

0.265

0.265

0.142

0.142

0.024

0.024

0.036

0.036

0.041

0.041

0.054

0.054

0.000

0.000

0.000

0.000

0.000

0.000

0.009

0.009

Years of compulsory

 Schooling

-0.123

-0.123

-0.064

-0.064

-0.061

-0.061

-0.013

-0.013

0.045

0.045

0.055

0.055

0.058

0.058

0.066

0.066

0.006

0.006

0.240

0.240

0.295

0.295

0.846

0.846

Constatnt

8.703

8.703

8.529

8.529

8.364

8.364

8.559

8.559

0.681

0.681

0.744

0.744

0.800

0.800

0.635

0.635

0.000

0.000

0.000

0.000

0.000

0.000

0.000

0.000

Dependent: Number of patent applications

Years of compulsory

Schooling

0.959

0.959

0.985

0.985

1.052

1.052

0.917

0.917

0.095

0.095

0.085

0.085

0.096

0.096

0.115

0.115

0.000

0.000

0.000

0.000

0.000

0.000

0.000

0.000

Constatnt

-2.649

-2.649

-2.920

-2.920

-3.558

-3.558

-1.731

-1.731

1.014

1.014

0.919

0.919

1.036

1.036

1.248

1.248

0.009

0.009

0.002

0.002

0.001

0.001

0.165

0.165

Legend: b/se/p

Source: EU-LFS 2016

 

Table B6: Models diagnostics

Employed 25-64

Low-educated, employed 25-64

Young (20-29) and

low-educated employed

Employed

migrants

Formal

Non-formal

Formal

Non-formal

Formal

Non-formal

Formal

Non-formal

Number of observations

1457560

1457560

252771

252771

29500

29500

151503

151503

BIC

4323386

4396472

729256

737449

87301

87509

531755

538223

AIC

4322630

4395716

728651

736833

86828

87036

531139

537607

Log-likelihood

-2161253

-2197796

-364267

-368358

-43357

-43461

-265508

-268742

Source: EU-LFS 2016

 


 

Table C: Robustness of the estimates to changes in the construction of the main explanatory variables (Formal AL)

Variable type

Model

Variable

A

B

C

D

E

Individual level barriers

Household related barriers

Female*care index

-0.092

-0.091

-0.091

-0.101

0.011

0.011

0.011

0.008

0.000

0.000

0.000

0.000

Male*care index

-0.070

-0.069

-0.069

-0.063

0.008

0.008

0.008

0.006

0.000

0.000

0.000

0.000

Male*not earners in the HH

0.170

0.165

0.166

0.097

0.084

0.084

0.084

0.071

0.043

0.049

0.049

0.173

Female*not earners in the HH

0.376

0.373

0.373

0.385

0.077

0.077

0.077

0.058

0.000

0.000

0.000

0.000

Working hours

-0.014

-0.014

-0.014

-0.015

0.002

0.002

0.002

0.001

0.000

0.000

0.000

0.000

Job related barriers

Low-skilled*Overeducation

0.026

0.023

0.022

0.064

0.066

0.009

0.009

0.009

0.013

0.013

0.002

0.007

0.011

0.000

0.000

High-skilled*Overeducation

0.004

0.001

0.000

-0.010

-0.012

0.008

0.008

0.007

0.008

0.009

0.611

0.894

0.999

0.231

0.176

Risk of computerisation

-0.236

-0.238

-0.239

-0.266

-0.247

0.056

0.056

0.056

0.058

0.058

0.000

0.000

0.000

0.000

0.000

High skilled occupation (dummy)

0.179

0.182

0.183

0.215

0.203

0.051

0.051

0.051

0.058

0.059

0.000

0.000

0.000

0.000

0.001

Supervision (dummy)

-0.079

-0.080

-0.080

-0.091

-0.133

0.034

0.034

0.034

0.037

0.036

0.022

0.019

0.020

0.013

0.000

Individual level control variables

Female

-0.038

-0.039

-0.039

-0.024

0.014

0.045

0.045

0.045

0.040

0.032

0.393

0.382

0.384

0.544

0.659

Age

-0.099

-0.099

-0.099

-0.105

-0.105

0.007

0.007

0.007

0.006

0.006

0.000

0.000

0.000

0.000

0.000

Level of education (primary ommited)

Lower_secondary

0.135

0.156

0.161

-0.234

-0.240

0.103

0.102

0.103

0.111

0.111

0.191

0.126

0.117

0.035

0.031

Upper_secondary

0.686

0.698

0.700

0.417

0.417

0.073

0.073

0.074

0.083

0.084

0.000

0.000

0.000

0.000

0.000

Tertiary

0.697

0.726

0.733

0.495

0.498

0.098

0.101

0.101

0.130

0.132

0.000

0.000

0.000

0.000

0.000

Looking for a job

0.308

0.306

0.307

0.240

0.307

0.054

0.054

0.054

0.037

0.038

0.000

0.000

0.000

0.000

0.000

Economic sector (public services ommited)

Agriculture

-0.795

-0.793

-0.793

-0.779

-0.877

0.121

0.121

0.121

0.074

0.073

0.000

0.000

0.000

0.000

0.000

Industry

-0.824

-0.824

-0.825

-0.841

-0.875

0.042

0.042

0.042

0.039

0.039

0.000

0.000

0.000

0.000

0.000

Construction

-1.008

-1.005

-1.006

-1.055

-1.109

0.067

0.067

0.067

0.061

0.060

0.000

0.000

0.000

0.000

0.000

Private services

-0.558

-0.557

-0.557

-0.536

-0.569

0.033

0.033

0.033

0.027

0.027

0.000

0.000

0.000

0.000

0.000

Degree of urbalization (City ommited)

Town

-0.289

-0.295

-0.295

-0.352

-0.376

0.046

0.045

0.045

0.034

0.036

0.000

0.000

0.000

0.000

0.000

Rural

-0.419

-0.428

-0.428

-0.468

-0.507

0.052

0.051

0.051

0.042

0.045

0.000

0.000

0.000

0.000

0.000

Subjective costs of AL

0.014

0.009

-0.007

-0.013

0.016

0.016

0.021

0.021

0.391

0.604

0.729

0.532

System determinants

Demography

Mean age of the regional population

-0.026

-0.030

-0.030

-0.026

-0.023

0.016

0.014

0.015

0.018

0.018

0.108

0.039

0.035

0.149

0.220

Initial education

Years of compulsory schooling

-0.155

-0.152

-0.141

-0.165

0.054

0.051

0.065

0.068

0.004

0.003

0.031

0.015

Entrance age into lower secondary education

0.381

0.379

0.389

0.384

0.427

0.060

0.059

0.059

0.066

0.067

0.000

0.000

0.000

0.000

0.000

Share of students in vocational programmes

0.002

0.007

0.007

0.005

0.004

0.004

0.005

0.004

0.006

0.006

0.682

0.133

0.115

0.426

0.483

Public expenditures on education

-0.276

-0.199

-0.214

-0.176

-0.214

0.086

0.064

0.060

0.079

0.081

0.001

0.002

0.000

0.027

0.008

Labour market

Employment rate

0.013

0.009

0.009

0.007

0.004

0.004

0.004

0.004

0.005

0.005

0.000

0.052

0.032

0.215

0.414

Share of dismissals

-0.006

-0.002

-0.003

0.000

-0.001

0.005

0.004

0.004

0.005

0.005

0.237

0.618

0.534

0.982

0.874

Share of temporary contracts

0.004

0.007

0.005

-0.007

-0.007

0.010

0.010

0.009

0.012

0.012

0.678

0.473

0.527

0.555

0.534

Active Labour Market Policy expenditure on Training

0.550

0.055

0.099

0.036

0.061

0.395

0.355

0.322

0.428

0.437

0.164

0.878

0.758

0.933

0.889

Economy

Regional GDP

0.625

0.591

0.600

0.663

0.753

0.093

0.095

0.090

0.121

0.122

0.000

0.000

0.000

0.000

0.000

Number of patent applications

0.014

0.099

0.095

0.093

0.103

0.035

0.057

0.052

0.067

0.069

0.681

0.080

0.070

0.162

0.139

Legend: b/se/p

Note:

Model A: Average regional years of schooling used instead of the Compulsory years of schooling

Model B: All sub-equations (associations between explanatory variables) dropped

Model C: Subjective assessment of costs being the main obstacle to AL participation dropped

Model D: Sub-equation on working hours dropped

Model E: Sub-equation on working hours dropped and working hours dropped from the list of explanatory variables

Source: EU-LFS 2016

 

 

 



[1] Approximately 16.7% of those participating in formal AL, and 6.3% of those participating in non-formal AL. 

[2] Based on the number of persons employed in the local unit (variable SIZEFIRM).